4th General Report on Political Monitoring of the Implementation of the European Charter of Local Self-Government: “The financial resources of local authorities in relation to their responsibilities: a litmus test for subsidiarity” (Application of Article 3, paragraph 1, Article 4, paragraphs 1-5 and Article 9 of the Charter) - CPL (7) 3 Part II

(20/04/00)

Rapporteur: Mr Jean-Claude FRECON (France)

---------------------------

EXPLANATORY MEMORANDUM

FOREWORD

I. INTRODUCTION

1. With the agreement of the Committee of Ministers and on the basis of the explanatory report on the European Charter of Local Self-Government, the Congress assumed responsibility for the political monitoring of the Charter’s implementation in the signatory states. Monitoring is therefore the direct responsibility of local elected representatives, who are ultimately the real beneficiaries of the Charter’s provisions.

To monitor the implementation of the Charter, the Congress, from its inception, set up a working group for which I am the rapporteur. The group, comprising 10 members of the Chamber of Local Authorities, is chaired by Mr Gerhard ENGEL (Germany) and assisted by a group of independent experts, led by Professor Alain DELCAMP (France).

2. The working group examines the legal foundations of local self-government and the conditions in which it operates in states which have merely signed the Charter. The examination procedure therefore functions as a political incentive rather than as a system of legal penalties. It aims to respect the wide variety of models and practices concerning local self-government in the various European states and does not seek to standardise them. Accordingly, the working group endeavours to take account of each state’s individual characteristics and to interpret the Charter’s provisions progressively.

3. Owing perhaps to their combined political and legal nature, these activities are a powerful political means for the Congress to encourage recognition of the fundamental principles of local democracy by the Council of Europe’s member states. The monitoring system employed by the Congress is therefore a particularly suitable compromise solution for ensuring compliance with an international treaty dealing with the internal organisation of individual states.

4. The working group carries out its tasks in two ways:

b) examining direct complaints from local authorities alleging that their own state authorities have failed to comply with the Charter’s provisions.

II. THE FIRST THREE REPORTS ON MONITORING THE IMPLEMENTATION OF THE EUROPEAN CHARTER OF LOCAL SELF-GOVERNMENT

5. In this context, taking account of the work carried out by the former Conference of Local and Regional Authorities, the working group’s first report on monitoring the implementation of the Charter (Rapporteur: Mr Jean-Claude VAN CAUWENBERGHE (Belgium)) considered in some depth the preliminary issues of the incorporation of the Charter into the legal systems of ratifying countries and the remedies available to local authorities in cases where the principle of local self-government is violated by domestic laws and regulations. Moreover, a significant part of this first report was devoted to the conformity of legislation in the above-mentioned countries with the various provisions of the Charter.

6. After it had been approved by the working group, the report was presented at the first plenary session of the Congress (31 May - 3 June 1994) by Mr Giorgio DE SABBATA (Italy). On the basis of the report and in accordance with the working group’s proposals, the Congress adopted Recommendation 2 (1994) to the Committee of Ministers and Resolution 3 (1994). Hence, these texts represent the first result of the CLRAE’s ex officio monitoring of the implementation of the European Charter of Local Self-Government.

7. In its Recommendation 2 (1994), the Congress noted that the Charter had been incorporated into domestic law in some countries, but not in others. It consequently requested the Committee of Ministers to study these issues and to inform it about the existence of procedures which local authorities could use to verify the conformity of domestic legislation with the Charter in countries which had ratified the Charter, whether or not it had been incorporated into domestic law.

8. The Committee of Ministers responded to this request by informing the Congress of its decision “to ask the Steering Committee on Local and Regional Authorities (CDLR) to provide it with the information it needed to reply to CLRAE Recommendation 2 (1994)”. At its 16th meeting (Strasbourg, 6-8 December 1995), the CDLR adopted a report (CM (96) 8 Addendum revised) providing the Committee of Ministers with the information it needed to reply to the Congress’s Recommendation 2 (1994). The report contains the information sent to the CDLR by 21 national delegations.

9. The Committee of Ministers submitted the CDLR’s report to the Congress. In its Resolution 34 (1996), the Congress took note of the report and decided to submit it to the working group responsible for monitoring the implementation of the Charter, for more thorough examination. The working group decided to undertake an analysis comparing the CDLR’s report, which contained the replies of the various ministries responsible for local authorities, with the summary of information provided by members of the group of independent experts and contained in the first report on monitoring the implementation of the Charter, drafted by Mr VAN CAUWENBERGHE in 1994.

10. On the basis of this analysis, the working group drew up a response as well as a draft recommendation proposing that the Committee of Ministers adopt a recommendation on the implementation of the European Charter of Local Self-Government, to be addressed to all ratifying countries. Ms Gaye DOGANOGLU (Turkey) and Mr Alan LLOYD (United Kingdom), rapporteurs, presented these documents at a meeting of the Standing Committee of the Congress (Strasbourg, 5 and 6 February 1998), which unanimously adopted the working group’s proposals set out in Recommendation 39 (1998). The Committee of Ministers gave a negative reply to the recommendation in its decision CM (99) 100 of 8-9 September 1999.

11. At the same time as drafting this response concerning the Charter’s incorporation into the legal system of ratifying countries and legal protection of local self-government, the working group continued to monitor the implementation of the Charter. It thus prepared a second report on the monitoring of local authorities by central and regional authorities. On the basis of this text, at its 3rd plenary session (Strasbourg, 2-4 July 1996) the Congress adopted Recommendation 20 (1996), dealing, inter alia, with the application of Article 7, paragraph 1 and Article 8 of the Charter, which it submitted to the Committee of Ministers. On this occasion, the Congress also adopted the above-mentioned Resolution 34 (1996). These texts represent the culmination of the second ex officio monitoring assignment concerning the implementation of the Charter.

12. In order to reply to Recommendation 20, the Committee of Ministers again requested the CDLR’s opinion. At its 20th meeting (Strasbourg, 26-28 November 1997), the CDLR proposed that the Committee of Ministers “transmit to all member states the CLRAE report on the application of all the above-mentioned articles and elaborate a recommendation of the Committee of Ministers to all member states concerning the control on local authorities’ actions, giving consideration to the proposals in paragraph 9 of CLRAE Recommendation 20 (1996)”.

13. The procedure followed in the preparation of the first three reports on monitoring the implementation of the Charter ensured a detailed, successful dialogue from beginning to end between the Congress, responsible for the political monitoring of the Charter’s implementation, and the signatory states, with the Committee of Ministers acting as intermediary. Nevertheless, the working group observed a number of weaknesses in the procedure, one major drawback being its length.

14. This report is the result of extremely fruitful co-operation between our working group and the CDLR. At its 25th meeting (Strasbourg, 7-9 June 2000), the CDLR is expected to adopt a draft recommendation on “Local taxation, financial equalisation and financial grants to local authorities” with a view to its final adoption by the Committee of Ministers. The co-operation procedure developed on the basis of Resolution 34 (1996) has enabled the Congress to state its views on the draft recommendation through the Standing Committee’s adoption in March 2000 of an opinion drawn up by the working group (Opinion … (2000)). The opinion took account of the conclusions of the present report on the financial resources of local authorities in relation to their responsibilities. A preliminary version of these conclusions was forwarded to the CDLR by the Congress President in November 1999 to enable the CDLR to take them into account in drawing up the draft recommendation of the Committee of Ministers on local taxation, financial equalisation and financial grants to local authorities.

III. THE FIRST THREE INTERNATIONAL CONFERENCES ON THE CHARTER

15. In order to examine more closely the issues dealt with in the reports and to demonstrate the Charter’s potential (following the conference held in Barcelona from 23 to 25 January 1992, which played a decisive part in the setting up of a genuine system for monitoring the implementation of the Charter as part of the Congress’s activities), the working group has organised other specific international conferences:

a) the conference celebrating the 10th anniversary of the European Charter of Local Self-Government (Copenhagen, 17-18 April, 1996), which, on the basis of an appraisal of the Charter’s implementation ten years after its opening for signature, revealed its widespread application, the broad range of situations to which it applies and the intention of European states, especially the new democracies in central and eastern Europe, to refer to it in their domestic legal systems;

b) the conference on the application of the European Charter of Local Self-Government by the courts (Barcelona, 24-26 April 1997), which highlighted the fact that although the activities involved in the monitoring of the Charter’s implementation by the Congress are essential, they form only the international component of the procedures for applying its provisions and that judicial supervision by national courts and tribunals should be the other essential element of these activities.

IV. FOURTH REPORT ON “THE FINANCIAL RESOURCES OF LOCAL AUTHORITIES IN RELATION TO THEIR RESPONSIBILITIES: A LITMUS TEST FOR SUBSIDIARITY”

16. The subject of the fourth general report on the Charter’s implementation (following the first three reports on the incorporation of the Charter into the legal systems of ratifying countries and the question of monitoring) was determined by the working group at its second meeting in Strasbourg in 1996, when it immediately stressed the importance of local authorities’ financial resources (Article 9 of the Charter) with regard to their political and administrative autonomy. This was also the theme of one of the conferences of European ministers responsible for local government (Lisbon, 10 and 11 October 1996). In the same context, the working group also considered the impact the introduction of the single currency would have on local authorities in the European Union, whose resources might be cut to enable countries to meet the macro-economic conditions required by the Maastricht Treaty. It concluded that local democracy would cease to exist if financial resources were insufficient and that the fourth report should therefore be devoted to the issue of local finances.

17. The group also felt that the practical application of two major articles of the Charter still needed further examination: Article 9 on local finances and Article 4 on the scope of local self-government. Accordingly, in view of the relationship between local authorities’ responsibilities and the resources needed to exercise them, it decided to examine the issue of local finances together with that of responsibilities.

18. After its initial examination of the replies to the questionnaire on local finances submitted by members of the group of independent experts, the working group selected a number of specific issues which merited particular attention:

- the concept of local taxes and the right of local authorities to determine the rate of these taxes;

- the respective proportions of general and specific (earmarked) grants in local budgets;
- the unstable and precarious nature of the sources of local authority funding;
- central authorities’ increasingly supervisory role with regard to local authority budgets;
- the impact of national financial difficulties on local self-government, particularly in countries having to meet criteria laid down in the Maastricht Treaty;
- public opinion concerning local taxes and the pros and cons of the joint financing of public projects by the state and regional or local authorities.

19. The study provided the working group with detailed information on the way in which local budgets have developed in the various countries, the level of local taxes (exclusively local taxes) in local budgets, the distinction between municipal taxes (which have the same basis of assessment as state taxes but whose rate is determined by the municipalities) and shared taxes (which are levied and whose rate is determined by the state), the concept of adequacy, resources procured through capital raising, local property tax and local corporation tax. The study showed in particular that local authorities in only eight European countries could boast a proportion of “own” resources higher than 50%. It pointed out that money raised through exclusive taxes was constantly falling, often being replaced by transfers. The working group believed that this constituted a restriction on the exercise of local self-government.

20. In the light of this information, Prof. Delcamp produced an initial questionnaire on local authorities’ responsibilities and whether they were commensurate with the financial resources available for exercising them. Using the experts’ replies as a basis, Mr Delcamp prepared a further study. After examining the study, the working group decided to review the timetable of its work on the final report. This change of approach was due to the difficulties of drafting a single text dealing with local authorities’ financial resources in relation to their responsibilities. More specifically, the working group had to come to terms with a wide variety of different practices regarding the transfer and delegation of powers to local authorities. Every country has its own established way of doing this, each based on different principles such as general responsibility or the listing of specific responsibilities.

21. Analysing these different systems in relation to local finances proved an especially complex task since very few members of the group of independent experts replied to the questionnaire on responsibilities and the only statistics available to the working group were those contained in tables drawn up by the CDLR for its publications on the functioning of local self-government in the member states. In the circumstances, the working group thought that it was very difficult to verify the financial resources available to local authorities to enable them to carry out their tasks. While remaining convinced that linking responsibilities to financial resources in a single report was politically expedient, the group thought that the balance between the two was also dependent on national political and institutional factors which should be studied in greater depth and incorporated into the final report, if it were to be truly complete.

22. Bearing these difficulties in mind, the working group decided to present at the 5th plenary session (Strasbourg, 26-28 May 1998), a preliminary report dealing only with local finances and simply opening the debate on the relationship between resources and responsibilities. On the basis of this interim report concerning only the financial resources of local authorities, the Congress adopted Resolution 71 (1998) at the 5th plenary session and instructed the working group to continue its efforts to draw up a final report also covering the question of responsibilities. Encouraged by the Congress’s instructions, the working group therefore continued its work on drawing up the final report on the relationship between the financial resources and responsibilities of local authorities.

23. To that end, a second questionnaire concerning matters such as the apportionment of specific responsibilities among local authorities was sent to the members of the group of independent experts on the Charter. The working group was eventually able to draw up a detailed report on the subject using the replies it received. However, in view of the complex, political nature of the question of whether financial resources were commensurate with responsibilities, the working group decided to seek validation of its work at a further international conference. At the invitation of the President of the Marches Regional Council, the conference was held in Ancona (Italy) from 16 to 18 October 1999.

24. The working group’s aim in holding the conference was to show that the balance between local authorities’ financial resources and responsibilities could have far-reaching implications for their political relations with higher-level authorities, whether central or regional. The extent to which resources are commensurate with responsibilities is the true yardstick of the degree of autonomy enjoyed by local authorities. The working group therefore considered that if the transfer of certain responsibilities to local authorities was accepted as one of the fundamental criteria for local self-government, it should also be acknowledged that the transfer of such responsibilities should always be offset by the allocation of sufficient resources.

25. In this connection, the discussions at the Ancona Conference provided a clear illustration that:

- proportionality between local authorities’ financial resources and their responsibilities is a litmus test for subsidiarity and hence for the degree of autonomy enjoyed by such authorities.

26. These ideas were encouraged by the Congress President, who, in his opening address at the conference, was anxious to point out that proper application of the subsidiarity principle was a practical way of ensuring effective, open government decisions, adapting them to the needs of citizens, maintaining the diversity that was an asset to our continent and, lastly, promoting sustainable development based on high standards of democracy.

27. In order to exercise these responsibilities, local and regional authorities must have sufficient financial resources of their own, which are freely available and commensurate with their powers. Using the working group’s initial conclusions as a basis, the Ancona Conference provided a number of indications as to whether European local and regional authorities actually possess sufficient resources for the responsibilities assigned or delegated to them. These indications have now been incorporated into this report, enabling us to assess the extent to which the principle of subsidiarity is currently applied in Europe.

28. Admittedly, in view of the difficulty of the task with which the working group has been entrusted, the report as it now stands is probably still unable to provide an accurate overview of the relationship between resources and responsibilities. However, it is to be hoped that the conclusions of this fourth report on monitoring the implementation of the Charter will serve as a useful step in this direction.

29. Besides the discussions at the Ancona Conference, the conclusions of this report are based on the two studies that the group of independent experts, led by Mr Alain Delcamp, has carried out since 1996: the first (Volume I of this report) deals with financial resources and, as stated above, was presented to you at the Congress’s 5th plenary session; the second (Volume II of this report) deals with responsibilities and is being presented for the first time.

30. On the basis of these conclusions, as rapporteur for the Working Group on the European Charter of Local Self-Government, I would urge you to adopt the draft recommendation and the draft resolution relating to this report.

V. CONCLUDING REMARKS

31. The working group regards the 7th CLRAE plenary session, in the year 2000, as a milestone in the Congress’s political monitoring of the implementation of the European Charter of Local Self-Government. In this context, as we have seen, the working group responsible for monitoring has completed four monitoring assignments under its ex officio procedure. This has led the Congress to adopt a considerable number of recommendations and resolutions addressed to the Committee of Ministers and the relevant authorities in the Council of Europe’s member states. These texts have probably played a part in strengthening local self-government in the member states. They have certainly led to frank, constructive dialogue with the relevant authorities. In our opinion, such dialogue is in itself a major achievement.

32. Following this CLRAE plenary session, the Council of Europe is to publish, by the end of 2000, at the working group’s request, a high-quality book emphasising the Congress’s various efforts to encourage states to adopt the Charter, to ensure compliance with the Charter in practice and to develop and operate our monitoring system.

33. In addition, in monitoring implementation of the Charter at the request of individual authorities over the past two years, the working group has examined a number of complaints from local authorities alleging infringements of the Charter by higher-level authorities. While ensuring that the legitimacy of decisions taken by the central authorities is respected, the working group has attempted to give an encouraging reply to all those who have submitted complaints, in the hope of improving the situation that caused them to complain.

34. In some cases, where there have been serious, blatant infringements of the Charter, the working group has immediately referred the matter to the Congress Bureau so that the Bureau may intervene on a political level and a report may be drawn up by the appropriate CLRAE authorities.

35. Before saying a few words about the future, I would like, on behalf of our Congress, to express my warmest thanks to the group of independent experts which has assisted the working group since 1994 and without which it would have been impossible to obtain the results described above. In particular, we should express our profound gratitude to Mr Alain Delcamp, chair of the group of independent experts, whose skills, political nous and approachability have enabled him to direct and guide our work over the years, ensuring co-ordination and continuity which would otherwise have been impossible.

36. The substantial reforms being approved at this plenary session will mean that the Congress takes on a new identity, becoming stronger and pursuing even more ambitious objectives.

37. These decisions are to be welcomed as, in my view, they are a recognition of the Congress’s efforts over the past few years. By formalising the Congress’s activities on monitoring the Charter, the Committee of Ministers no doubt wished to contribute towards strengthening both the Congress itself and European legal safeguards for local self-government.

THE FINANCIAL RESOURCES OF LOCAL AUTHORITIES

Study prepared as part of the

4th General Report on Political Monitoring of the Implementation of the European Charter of Local Self-Government: “The financial resources of local authorities in relation to their responsibilities: a litmus test for subsidiarity”

(Application of Article 3, paragraph 1, Article 4, paragraphs 1-5 and Article 9 of the Charter)

by Alain DECAMP
Chairman of the Group of Independent Experts on the European Charter of Local Self-Government

Volume I

FOREWORD

I. Step three in monitoring the implementation of the european charter of local self-government: the question of financial autonomy

II. METHODOLOGICAL PROBLEMS RAISED BY A COMPARATIVE STUDY OF LOCAL FINANCIAL RESOURCES:

III. THE PROVISIONS OF THE EUROPEAN CHARTER OF LOCAL SELF-GOVERNMENT RELATED TO FINANCES

IV. GENERAL DATA ON LOCAL BUDGETS

Country

Initials

% GDP

% GGE

Reference year

%GDP

%GGE

Reference year

Albania

AL

7.7

25.4

1995

     

Austria

A

12.71

20.18

1993

12

15.2

1994

Belgium

B

4.9

10.9

1993

7.4

11.2

1995

Bulgaria

BG

9

20

1994

     

Cyprus

CY

1.4

4.1

1993

     

Croatia

CR

           

Czech Republic

CS

9.3

20.9

1994

     

Denmark20

DK

19.9

31.28

1994

     

Estonia

EE

7.1

17.6

1994

     

Finland

SF

18

29.5

1993

23

   

France

F

5.54

27.22

1992

9.2

19

1995

Germany

D

8.12

28.69

1993

10

16.7

1995

Greece

GR

3.33

5.6

1989

2.1

5.6

1995

Hungary

H

17

53

1994

 

14.1

1997

Iceland

IS

9.1

22.3

1994

 

22

1996

Ireland

IRL

4.9

13.8

1994

5.4

 

1994

Italy

I

7

13

1993

13.7

 

1995

Latvia

LV

12.45

24

1994

 

19

1997

Lithuania

LT

13.1

58.8

1993

10

35.2

1996

Luxembourg

L

9.92

32.3

1993

11.7

 

1994

Malta

M

0.337

0.629

1995

 

2

1996/7

Moldova

MOL

           

Netherlands

NL

13.3

23.1

1994

19.1

36.2

1994

Norway21

N

18.9

60

1994

11

40

 

Poland

PLK

7

21.6

1994

     

Portugal

P

4.6

9.7

1993

3.7

12

1994

Romania

RO

3.5

16.9

1993

     

Russian Fed

SU

           

Saint-Marino

SM

0.11

0.19

1993

     

Slovakia

SL

4.79

11.78

1994

     

Slovenia

SV

4.4

10.1

1995

 

10

1995

Spain

E

4.87

12.17

1994

7.2

 

1995

Sweden

S

27.5

38

1994

28.7

 

1994

Switzerland

CH

10.8

27.9

1993

     

Ex rep of Macedonia

FYR

       

1.46

1995

Turkey

TR

2.41

12.3

1992

3.3

 

1996

Ukraine

UKR

           

United Kingdom

UK

11

27

1994

10

25

1994/5

Average

 

8.91

22.12

       


4.3 The trend towards decentralisation

V THE ORIGIN OF THE DIFFERENT RESOURCES IN LOCAL BUDGETS AND THE ROLE OF LOCAL TAXES

The only tax, therefore, that may be considered as falling within the scope of this definition of loca taxes, is one, whether allocated to the community or created by it, whose amount may be freely varied by its elected representatives.

In our opinion, on the other hand, it does not seem possible to include in local taxes what is commonly referred to in the United Kingdom as "shared taxes", i.e. taxes collected at the national level before being redistributed to several levels of authorities.

The origin of the resources in local budgets33

Country

Initials

Local taxes

Fees and charges

Transfers

Capital raising

Other

Albania

AL

2.50

3.00

94.00

0.00

0.50

Austria

A

16.30

21.00

43.70

10.00

9.00

Belgium

B

40.75

6.00

44.26

0.00

8.99

Bulgaria

BG

1.00

10.00

78.00

2.00

9.00

Cyprus

CY

25.00

33.00

30.00

12.00

0.00

Croatia

CR

         

Czech Republic

CS

16.00

12.00

45.00

11.00

16.00

Denmark

DK

52.20

22.30

24.50

0.00

1.00

Estonia

EE

0.10

0.90

91.00

2.00

6.00

Finland

SF

39.50

24.00

28.40

5.60

2.50

France

F

42.00

8.00

29.00

9.00

12.00

Germany

D

35.00

4.00

32.00

7.00

0.00

Greece

GR

27.00

8.00

63.00

2.00

0.00

Hungary

H

13.00

8.17

63.61

6.71

8.51

Iceland

IS

16.00

21.00

57.00

0.00

7.00

Ireland

IRL

64.20

18.00

5.40

4.60

7.80

Italy

I

31.00

11.00

42.00

7.00

10.00

Latvia

LV

65.00

1.00

29.00

0.00

5.00

Lithuania

LT

6.40

0.00

87.30

0.00

6.30

Luxembourg

L

32.88

24.88

33.16

8.00

0.00

Malta

M

0.50

0.00

97.80

0.00

1.70

Moldova

MOL

         

Netherlands

NL

15.00

2.00

83.00

0.00

0.00

Norway

N

47.50

12.80

36.20

0.00

3.50

Poland

PLK

21.00

7.00

60.00

0.00

12.00

Portugal

P

23.00

10.80

49.30

7.50

9.40

Romania

RO

5.00

16.00

79.00

0.00

0.00

Russian Fed

SU

22.00

2.50

72.50

0.00

3.00

Saint-Marino

SM

0.00

0.00

31.00

69.00

0.00

Slovakia

SL

10.00

9.00

39.00

5.00

37.00

Slovenia

SV

6.80

13.90

79.30

0.00

0.00

Spain

E

29.80

18.50

27.10

14.90

9.70

Sweden

S

56.00

15.00

20.00

0.00

9.00

Switzerland

CH

46.00

24.00

18.00

3.00

9.00

Ex rep of Macedonia

FYR

62.30

28.80

1.50

0.00

7.40

Turkey

TR

4.76

20.90

48.86

0.00

25.48

Ukraine

UKR

         

United Kingdom

UK

25.00

11.00

53.00

8.00

4.00

Average

 

25.73

12.24

49.03

5.55

6.88

Average for data gathered by CDLR

 

18.33

11.72

50.88

6.94

12.14

The "capital raising" item seems relatively low (hardly more than 5%).

There then follows a second group with local tax shares ranging from 42% (France) to approximately 33% (Luxembourg), to which may be added Belgium, Finland and Germany. It is worth noting that the rate for France is only obtained due to taxes for which the bases of assessment are different from those used by the central State. This is also true of Germany, but only partially so.

VI THE STRUCTURE OF LOCAL TAXATION. THE DIFFERENT CATEGORIES OF TAXES

The different categories of local taxes39

 

Property tax

Income tax

Household tax

Business and Trade Taxes

Other

 

B

NB

   

Consom-mation

Entreprises

Mutations

 

Austria

I E

I E

   

I E

     

Belgium

F T

 

F T

   

F T

 

F T

Denmark

I E

F E

I E

         

Finland

I E

 

I T

         

France

I E

I E

 

I E

 

I E

 

F T

Former Y. Rep. of Macedonia

 

I A

       

I A

 

Germany

F T

F T

     

F T

   

Greece

 

I A

   

I A

   

F T

Hungary

I E

           

F T

Ireland

I E

             

Iceland

I E

 

I T

       

F E

Italy

I E

     

I E

 

F T

Latvia

I A

I E

           

Lithuania

 

I E

         

F E

Luxembourg

I E

     

I E

   

Malta

         

I A

   

Netherlands

F E

   

F E

     

F E

Norway

F E

           

I E

Portugal

I A

I E

F E

 

I A

 

I A

F A

Russia

 

F E

     

F E

 

F E

Slovenia

F E

       

I E

I E

Spain

I E

   

I E

I E

F E

F E

Sweden

   

I E

       

F T

Turkey

I A

   

I A

   

I A

United Kingdom

F E

           

This brief overview in any case shows that there is no ideal local taxation system, and that attempting to localise, as a factor contributing to self-government, only limits the imagination - generally considered to be fertile where taxes are concerned - of reformers in this particular area.

VII THE FUNCTION, NATURE AND DISTRIBUTION OF TRANSFERS

Table 4: Breakdown of Transfers - Figures as a percentage of general municipal revenue

Country

Initials

Shared taxes

General Grants

Specific Grants

Other

Albania

AL

1

59

29

5

Austria

A

26

1

0

8

Belgium

B

0

25

5

10

Bulgaria

BG

34

37

7

0

Cyprus

CY

0

7

22

1

Croatia

CR

       

Czech Republic

CS

23

8

10

4

Denmark

DK

2

12

0

11

Estonia

EE

60

27

4

0

Finland

SF

1

28

1

0

France

F

0

24

0

2

Germany

D

17

15

13

0

Greece

GR

25

25

0

8

Hungary

H

7

52

5

2

Iceland

IS

43

7

1

2

Ireland

IRL

0

11

46

0

Italy

I

2

8

24

5

Latvia

LV

23

35

6

3

Lithuania

LT

       

Luxembourg

L

24

2

0

11

Malta

M

0

91

0

7

Moldova

MOL

       

Netherlands

NL

0

54

4

3

Norway

N

0

17

14

2

Poland

PL

23

22

15

0

Portugal

P

1

31

4

2

Romania

RO

33

25

21

0

Russian Fed

SU

       

Saint-Marino

SM

0

31

0

0

Slovakia

SL

30

1

8

0

Slovenia

SV

       

Spain

E

0

8

29

0

Sweden

S

0

11

8

0

Switzerland

CH

1

3

14

0

Ex rep of Macedonia

FYR

       

Turkey

TR

3

0

3

51

Ukraine

UKR

       

United Kingdom

UK

17

32

27

0

Average

 

12.77

22.87

10.32

4.42

7.1.2 Assistance: specific grants and general grants

7.1.3 Financial equalisation

One can easily understand under these conditions why the switch-over from specific to general grants has been fostered by the Council of Europe, and the trend in fact does seem to have been in that direction if we consider the relative average share today for each of these categories of transfers, representing respectively 22.87% and 10.32% of local resources, or a general grant level that has more than doubled, without taking into account the shared taxes which further increase the portion of transfers that authorities may freely dispose of.

The policies adopted by the various countries in relation to the grant system seem relatively similar, but it is difficult, however, to give a systematic overview which is satisfactory, due to the variability, confusion and number of the considerations taken into account in the various systems. After an initial phase during which the concept of block grants has become generally accepted, the time has perhaps come to lay down a few simple principles which could serve as guidelines for assessing the compliance with the spirit of the Charter of the various policies implemented in terms of transfers.

firstly, the amount of grants and the method of establishing them at the national level (a question of even greater emphasis at a time when every state is obliged to adopt restrictive financial policies);
and secondly, the methods of their distribution, in order to prevent an indirect reversal to the over-sophistication of specific grants.

VIII FEES AND CHARGES, "OTHER" RESOURCES AND CAPITAL RAISING

through the fees and charges they levy in exchange for the services they provide to the population, through diverse receipts which may be temporary, for example the sale of assets or capital gains on investments when these are authorised,

and by income from capital raised with specialised institutions,

or, more rarely, from savings bonds, which local authorities are authorised to issue only under certain conditions and in certain countries.

Fees and charges, on average representing approximately 12%73, in fact are the second most important item in local resources after taxes. Just as for taxes - perhaps even more than taxes - their extent depends on the initiative of the local authority. There may be a statutory instrument concerning the prices of services, but these are now fairly rare.

CONCLUSION

LOCAL FINANCIAL RESOURCES AND LOCAL SELF-GOVERNMENT.

LESSONS TO BE LEARNT FROM THE IMPLEMENTATION OF THE CHARTER

However, it is clear that many references have been made to the way in which financial resources are inevitably linked to the number of tasks actually carried out. This is what we have called the question of adequacy.

Difficulty of assessing “adequacy”

- the difficulty of accurately defining the tasks actually carried out by local authorities as opposed to the state. The first problem here is a legal one: most countries, except federal states, perhaps – and even they may be unwilling - are reluctant to draw up a clear list of all local authorities’ responsibilities. Even if they were to produce such a list, local authorities' exact margin for manoeuvre would still have to be determined. The performance of these tasks is governed by law and often by regulations, which means that such tasks cannot be defined from a purely practical point of view.

- the difficulty of assessing the cost of the tasks carried out by the various types of local authority. Such an evaluation must be partly subjective and may be particularly difficult to carry out since the size of the task carried out may depend on the will or on the wealth of the particular authority concerned. Often, such costs can only be assessed in an approximate way, for example when a law transferring a particular responsibility is passed. Ideally, at such a time, the evaluation used to calculate the resources to be transferred should correspond to the budgetary payments made up to that point by the authority (central or regional) which was previously responsible.

- the difficulty of clearly defining various terms contained in the Charter.

Conclusions regarding the financial resources situation

Besides, and this is a fundamental point, the increasing frequency of transfers has coincided with the establishment of a kind of local democracy which is more “functional” than political, ie one which focuses on decision makers’ accountability to the people they are required to administer.

Unless we are careful, there is a danger that the growth of transfers, which is certainly useful if responsibilities are to be exercised consistently in both quantitative and geographical terms, will bring about a change in the role played by local councillors in Europe: instead of acting as managers, accountable for the monies entrusted to them by the people, they will be expected to negotiate with and even beg from the central or regional authorities. This is a danger about which we think the Congress, as the local authorities' representative body, could issue a warning in order to guard against the risk of governments relaxing as soon as they have introduced the system of non-earmarked transfers.

More than in the past, the need for monetary stability and the demands of the battle against unemployment could conveniently be used to justify such a policy. Hence the need for vigilance seems all the greater.

The average figure is less than 40% (38.69%), while six European Union countries, including one of the largest, are below that average - one of them with under 17% and the others with between 34% and 38%. As one would expect, none of the new democracies, except the two mentioned above and with the reservations stated, are above the average figure. These results which, of course, could be disputed, but not in terms of the overall picture they convey, could be used to alert people to the battles which lie ahead, if only to prevent the current situation from worsening.

- the difficulty of obtaining homogeneous information about local finances,

- the substantial but nevertheless limited proportion of "own resources" coming from real local taxes, ie taxes for which local authorities may be required to decide the rate, albeit within a framework of upper limits and bands.

- the trend towards a reduction in exclusive taxes, mainly as a result of the difficulty of finding alternative independent tax revenue, this being due both to central and regional governments' reluctance to give up progressive tax revenue and to the technical difficulties involved in replacing or supplementing traditional local taxes which either do not produce a high enough yield or are not "elastic" enough,

- the temptation to replace these with transferred resources,

- the predominant role to be played in future by transferred resources in funding local budgets, and the simultaneous increase in the proportions of these resources being made available for authorities to dispose of freely (general grants and shared taxes) to the detriment of earmarked resources (specific grants),

- a certain confusion between funding local budgets or compensating for powers and responsibilities transferred in various ways, and financial equalisation; the trend, noted in some countries, of insisting that the practices of local authorities are "standardised" to some extent, at least where taxes are concerned, and the danger that this poses to the exercise of local freedom, which naturally involves a certain amount of variety,

- the value of achieving within the Council of Europe, the only body which deals with local finances from a not exclusively economic viewpoint, a sufficient level of standardisation of budgetary statistics in order to clarify the concept of local authorities' "own resources", which they may dispose of freely,

- the relatively limited use made of capital raising and the fact that this possibility for funding local budgets gives central government the opportunity to continue exercising some form of supervision.

- the need, in order to assess the actual situation of local democracy in Europe, to be able to compare for each country the resources available (and the proportion of these represented by own resources) with the tasks to be carried out, or at least those that are obligatory;

- the difficulty of achieving this aim because of technical and legal problems: the inadequacy of current data on the distribution of responsibilities in different countries; uncertainties surrounding basic concepts and definitions of responsibilities contained in the Charter itself, which need to be clarified, probably by means of a chart analysing the interpretations made by the different countries; the reluctance of most member states to incorporate in a small number of general laws even a brief list of the main responsibilities of the various types of local authorities; the difficulty in any case of objectively assessing the cost of exercising these responsibilities.

- the expediency, even before carrying out a full study, of making the Congress aware of the above points, which need to be taken into account if conclusions drawn from current national situations are to be used to influence the policies of the governments concerned.

n Fees and charges
n Local taxes

RESPONSIBILITIES OF LOCAL AUTHORITIES AND PROPORTIONALITY BETWEEN RESPONSIBILITIES AND LOCAL FINANCES

Study prepared as part of the

4th General Report on Political Monitoring of the Implementation of the European Charter of Local Self-Government: “The financial resources of local authorities in relation to their responsibilities: a litmus test for subsidiarity”

(Application of Article 3, paragraph 1, Article 4, paragraphs 1-5 and Article 9 of the Charter)

by Alain DECAMP, Chairman, and Philippe DE BRUYCKER, Vice-Chairmane
of the Group of Independent Experts on the European Charter of Local Self-Government

Volume II

SUMMARY

INTRODUCTION AND REPLIES TO QUESTIONNAIRES

This report constitutes the second part of the monitoring work that the Council of Europe decided to undertake in 1998.

I. BACKGROUND TO THE REPORT

The summary presented this time is supplemented by the replies given to a second questionnaire sent out mid-way through the year and drawn up at the meeting of the Working Group responsible for follow-up on 7 and 8 April last. The questionnaire (which appears in the appendix together with the first version) included a table, responsibility by responsibility, of the different fields of public action likely to be assigned to local and regional authorities.

The replies received have enabled us to draw a number of conclusions which are acceptable at this stage and obviate the need, as had been envisaged in the preliminary report, to resort to monographs, often very complete (especially in the most recent versions) drawn up by the CDLR. As was the case for the report on finances, these documents will be referred to only to provide supplementary information. Nevertheless the aim is still to attempt, country by country, to harmonise the Congress sources with those of the CDLR in order to have data which could usefully be compared by reducing, as far as possible, any “technical” reasons for divergence, if only at the level of the terminology used.

II. REPLIES TO THE QUESTIONNAIRE

Of the 36 countries (out of the 40 Council of Europe member states) which have signed the European Charter of Local Self-Government, 29 provided at least one reply to the questionnaires sent to the members of the Committee of Independent Experts. Furthermore, one reply was received from a non-member country: Bosnia-Herzegovina.

III. CONCLUSIONS JUSTIFYING A SEPARATE REPORT ON RESPONSIBILITIES

Before looking at the various points, it is necessary, as has been customary practice in previous work, to take stock of the provisions of the Charter concerning responsibilities and to take this opportunity to clarify a number of definitions for better mutual understanding.

PART ONE - PRINCIPLES GOVERNING THE ALLOCATION OF RESPONSIBILITIES

I. THE CHARTER PROVISIONS AND THE ISSUES THEY RAISE

---

---

II. INTERPRETATION OF THE CHARTER PROVISIONS WITH REFERENCE TO THEIR APPLICATION IN THE DIFFERENT STATES

- apart from the question of how to distinguish in clear, practical terms not only between spheres of responsibility but also between aspects of the same sphere, it is clear that the choices involved are not merely technical ones and that, inevitably, not all spheres of responsibility lend themselves as readily as education to a detailed theoretical analysis. What about town planning, environment, or culture, for example?

PART TWO - THE REPLIES

I. GENERAL PROBLEMS OF ALLOCATING RESPONSIBILITIES

1. Levels of legislation

As we have seen, the concept of general responsibility only exists in the so-called “continental” systems, but it is clear from scanning the replies that this is the system adopted by all the newly democratic countries.

It is a pity that the criteria for distinguishing between own and delegated responsibilities are not always clear in the reports, nor apparently (and more worryingly as regards the exercise of local democracy) in the legislation.

The experts’ replies to question 5 are particularly original and show that the situation has evolved considerably.

II. LOCAL AND REGIONAL AUTHORITIES’ FIELDS OF RESPONSIBILITY IN THE DIFFERENT COUNCIL OF EUROPE MEMBER STATES

They have more responsibility - at least in some countries - for civil defence (there are different names for this area of activity). On the other hand, the fire service and the keeping of various registers of the population (civil status or electoral registers, for example) are traditionally local government responsibilities, except in certain countries such as Latvia and Lithuania.

With regard to roads, there is a very clear system of classification (particularly in Denmark and France) under which the different grades of road are the responsibility of either central government or one of the levels of local government. In the Scandinavian countries, roads that carry very little traffic may be the responsibility of the residents.

PART THREE - OUTLINE ASSESSMENT and THE QUESTION OF MATCHING RESOURCES AND OBLIGATIONS: THE SUFFICIENCY PRINCIPLE

I. DO LOCAL AUTHORITIES PLAY A SUBSTANTIAL PART IN PUBLIC AFFAIRS?

Municipal spending as a percentage of GDP

Municipal spending as a percentage of GDP

II. IS THERE A COUNCIL OF EUROPE MEMBER COUNTRIES’ MODEL FOR THE ALLOCATION OF RESPONSIBILITIES?

Relative importance of different areas of responsibility as indicated by local government spending
I- European Union countries109

Country

Denmark

France

Netherlands

Portugal

      United
      Kingdom110

Sweden

Reference unit

% (estimated for1998)

FF billions and %
(estimated for1998)

NLG millions 1995
and %

% 1996

£ millions
and %

% 1995

Level

Municipality

County

Municipality

Département

Region

Municipality

Province

Municipality

District

Municipality

County

Security, police
and courts

10,2111

       

1771(1,7%)

13

5112

873(15,9%) (3)

 

2%113

Education

13,5
(3)

12,8
(3)

 

17,4 (8,6%)
(3)

15,9 (35,5%)
(1)
(1)

7815(7,5%)
(3)

23

6

2721 (49,5%) (1)

31 %
(2)

5,6 %114
(3)

Health

28,5115
(2)

46,6
(1)

     

1428(1,4%)

62

13
(3)

1050 (19,1%) (2)

 

77%
(1)

Social action

29,7116
(1)

29,5117
(2)

 

65,4 (43,2%)
(1)

 

23368 (22,4%) (2)

4024 (49,5%) (1)

3

 

50 %
(1)

6,9%
(2)

Town and country planning

         

555(0,2%)

108

24118
(2)

     

Housing

       

3,9

50290 (47,8%) (1)

251

       

Environment

3,4

2,7

   

6

5249 (5,1%)

1336 (16,4%) (3)

3

466 (8,5%)

   

Culture,
leisure and sport

3,4

       

6089(5,9)

580

7

 

7 %

 

Traffic and
transport

 

8,5

 

26,4 (18,1%)
(2)
(1)

10,5 (23,5%)
(2)

7196(6,9)

1356 (16,6%) (2)

28
(1)

322 (5,9%)

8 %
(3)

 

Power supplies

         

642 (0,7)

26

       

Economic affairs

       

17,1 (10,8%) (3)

793 (0,8)

356

11

     

Other

     

30,1
(2)

       

63 (1,1 %)

4 %

7,4 %

Relative importance of different areas of responsibility as indicated by local government spending
II- Non European Union countries

Country

Estonia

Hungary

Iceland

Latvia

Norway

Poland

Ukraine

Reference unit

EEK billions
1998119 and %

%

ISK millions and %
(estimated for 1997)

% 1996

% 1997

% 1997

$ per head of population120 and %

Level

Municipalities

Municipalities

Municipalities

Municipalities

Local sector as a whole121

Municipalities

Municipalities

Security, police
and courts

0,17 (9,5)122

12123

1,2 (1,6%)

 

6124

10125

 

Education

0,6 (35,3)
(1)

31 ,75
(1)

15,7(30,1%)
(1)

27,5
(1)

25
(2)

37
(1)

50 (38,5)
(1)

Health

0,08 (4,7)

22,18
(2)

0,15 (0,3%)

23,2
(2)

22
(3)

6

23 (17,7)
(2)

Social action

0,18 (10,7)
(3)

12,05
(3)

10,5 (20,2) (2)

11,6

28
(2)

9
(3)

 

Town and country planning

 

11,58126

1,1 (2,1)

   

22 127
(2)

 

Housing

0,03 (1,5)

       

5

8 (6,2)
(3)

Environment

 

1,35

4,4 (8,5)

       

Culture,
leisure and sport

0,12 (6,9)

4,43

5,5 (10,5)
(3)

5,6

 

3

3

Traffic and
transport

0,2 (11,2)
(2)

 

4,6 (8,9)

   

2

 

Power supplies

       

6

   

Economic affairs

   

1,2 (2,3)

18,8
(3)

 

2

 

Other

20,2 %

3,52

3,6 (7,2)

 

13

   

III. IS THE PRINCIPLE OF BALANCE BETWEEN RESOURCES AND OBLIGATIONS (ie MATCHING FUNDING TO RESPONSIBILITIES) SECURE?

PART FOUR - MAIN CONCLUSIONS ON WHICH A RESOLUTION COULD BE BASED

I. Updating and interpreting the Charter with regard to responsibilities

- Show more clearly that the question of the nature of the responsibility (basic or specific) is secondary in relation to its definition and, above all, the level of regulation in which this definition should be given,

- Draw greater attention to the difference in nature between “own” powers and “delegated” powers. It needs to be shown that in the second case, the regulatory level is less important than in the first133, that it could even be a mere agreement with the local authority, but in the framework of a legislative definition of the general conditions of the contract (possibility of refusal, guarantee of financial resources).

- find a simpler and less imperative presentation of the general definition of responsibilities showing that above all this is an important question of legal philosophy for local self-government, in harmony with the principle of subsidiarity: anything which parliament has not explicitly proscribed or reserved for another authority may qualify for an initiative at local level.

- propose a method of defining and presenting responsibilities.

- seek practical ways and means of assessing the actual application of the principle of proportionality between responsibilities and the financial implications. This should be a general principle and not simply, as many states seem to interpret it, a principle which applies merely to delegated powers.

- redress the balance in the debate on mandatory responsibilities and optional responsibilities which is not as fundamental as is sometimes made out, except as a criterion for distinguishing clearly the powers and responsibilities which must of necessity be compensated for financially from the others.

II. Methods for defining and allocating powers (i) between the state and the decentralised or autonomous authorities and (ii) between the different levels of self-government.

- It must be clearly spelt out that the expression “full and exclusive” competences cannot be divorced from the context of the way in which the state is organised and that it must be combined with the principle of the hierarchical structure of regulatory texts and functions. It is not necessarily unlawful for central government to intervene in the implementation of a local or regional responsibility. Everything is a question of form and empowerment or not by parliament.

- “Vertical” or regulatory allocation between the state and the autonomous authorities:

- “horizontal” or sectoral allocation which raises the question of the criteria and practical interpretation of the principle of subsidiarity.

- It is out of the question to advocate an exclusive approach (general responsibilities or a list of competences). Experience has shown the misgivings and differences of approach in this field and how impossible it is to decide on a single method. A number of easily understandable ideas must be borne in mind:

▪ the level of protection of local responsibilities must be at least comparable to that of other aspects of self-government. The importance attached to this question must therefore be reassessed. Taking the example of what the new democracies have done, a list of responsibilities (in the sense of fields of action) should ideally be included in the constitution.

▪ Account must also be taken, above and beyond differences over the method to be adopted, of the advantages, together with some disadvantages, of including in the basic laws on local self-government provisions relating to responsibilities even if it means such responsibilities need to remain general in nature. In this way citizens will realise that questions of local self-government are not merely procedural questions but have a very practical impact on important areas concerning their life in society. Rather than an exhaustive listing, an indicative listing could be given, the application and development of which could be specified in particular laws.

▪ Similarly, an attempt could be made to group together in a suitable form all the provisions concerning local autonomy, irrespective of the field in question.

III. The balance between resources and obligations

- The principle of matching resources to obligations is stated clearly only in very few legislations. There is therefore no system for assessing how it is applied. Application of this principle would appear to be left to the good will of parliaments in the lottery of annual budgets. Guarantees that the principle will be upheld are therefore reduced to the bare minimum. What is more, when it is mentioned, the principle concerns only delegated responsibilities (which shows that the provisions of the Charter have not been understood) or transfers of responsibility in the future.

▪ The proportion of their resources deriving from own local taxation is generally small and indeed falling in the more developed countries.

▪ In the new democracies, the provision of sufficient own resources comes up against the difficulty of drawing up a property index, insufficient economic development and income (industrial or private) and conceptual difficulties inherent in a complete overhaul of the system of organisation.

▪ the taxes they are allowed to levy are, without exception, not the most productive. There is still greater emphasis on property and land tax whereas taxes on economic activity are continually falling on the pretext of the principle of free competition.

▪ in the EU countries and in the countries which are candidates for membership, the desire for a strict budgetary policy is often reflected in larger overall financial constraints, from which local authorities do not escape. Worse still, this may result in a loss of their independence or a questioning of the decentralisation itself, held to be partly responsible for the growing public deficit.

▪ in other states, financial difficulties caused by the transition make it tempting to decentralise responsibilities – which may appear to satisfy the requirements of the Charter – without, however, allocating the corresponding resources.

- to demand the setting up of joint state-local authority committees to evaluate the current balance between resources and obligations

- to demand, if the decentralisation of new taxes is not feasible, the conclusion of financial stability pacts to ensure stability of local finances, particular as we saw in the preceding report that these resources are increasingly dependent on budgetary decisions taken by central government.

- the major associations of local elected representatives could also be encouraged to give some thought to the optimum level of division of responsibilities between the state and local authorities:

▪ with each new envisaged transfer of responsibility there must be a corresponding method of funding, whether this concerns the transfer of a new tax resource or new transfer funding. The latter should, wherever possible, not be tied to the responsibility itself but should be allocated to all the resources available to the authority to enable greater scope for savings to be made.

▪ the first question to be asked relates to an evaluation of the amounts concerned. Generally speaking, and ideally, the solution should be to transfer to the authority the equivalent of the amount central government would have spent on that responsibility. However, experience has clearly shown that local authorities, generally closer to the needs of their populations, do a better job of managing the sectors assigned to them than the central authorities. It is essential therefore that transferred resources be open-ended (as is the case with taxes) or that they may be re-assessed. Local authorities are therefore advised to be very circumspect with regard to the transfer of responsibility offered to them. It is essential for them to clearly state their views at that point.

APPENDICES

1. Questionnaires sent to the experts

2. Classification adopted for the CDLR's study series

1. Questionnaires sent to the experts

1.1. First questionnaire

QUESTIONNAIRE ON THE RESPONSIBILITIES OF LOCAL AUTHORITIES
addressed to the members of the Committee of Independent Experts on the European Charter of Local Self-Government

Preliminary observations

1. What are the general principles governing the responsibilities of local authorities and the nature of their powers?

2. How are those responsibilities defined:

3. To what extent are local authorities assigned ad hoc powers in order to fulfil specific duties?

4. Do local authorities have the right to take action in fields which are not specifically excluded from their general responsibilities or assigned to other bodies? Is that right acknowledged in law or in the Constitution or does it result from the general principles of interpretation in force?

5. To what extent is the principle of subsidiarity, as set out in Article 4, paragraph 3 of the European Charter of Local Self-Government, enshrined in standard-setting texts and implemented in practice?

6. Are the general responsibilities of local authorities full, comprehensive and exclusive?

7. Is a distinction made in your legislation between own responsibilities and delegated responsibilities? Is this distinction based on a specific criterion?

8. To what extent and according to which criteria are local authorities required to carry out duties which are the responsibility of higher authorities?

9. In decreasing order of importance and, if possible, grouped under main headings but giving sufficient detail, please list the responsibilities135 discharged by:

1.2. Second questionnaire

This second questionnaire is slightly different from the first and is more comprehensive, especially with regard to the precise definition of local responsibilities. The experts who replied to the first questionnaire are kindly asked to elaborate on their previous answers and to reply to the new questions.

1. What are the general principles governing the distribution of responsibilities between local and central authorities?

2. What are the most common categories used to classify responsibilities (discretionary/compulsory, legislative/executive, etc)? Is a distinction made between purely local interests, general interests and interests combining local and general elements?

3. In particular, please indicate whether a distinction is made between own responsibilities and delegated responsibilities. If so, what is the criterion governing it, at what level (legislation, case-law, practice, theory) is it made and what impact does it have (particularly in terms of supervision, financing and liability)?

4. How are responsibilities defined:

5. Do local authorities have the right to take action in fields which are not specifically excluded from their general responsibilities or assigned to other bodies? Is that right acknowledged in law or in the Constitution or does it result from the general principles of interpretation in force? In what circumstances might a local authority be prohibited from taking action in a particular field?

6. To what extent is the principle of subsidiarity, as set out in Article 4, paragraph 3 of the European Charter of Local Self-Government, recognised? Is it the basis on which responsibilities are distributed or is it a requirement to be complied with by the various authorities in carrying out their responsibilities?

7. Do local authorities have the opportunity to give their point of view concerning changes in their responsibilities (in particular through consultation procedures)?

8. Are the general responsibilities of local authorities full, comprehensive and exclusive?

9. Are local authorities genuinely able to carry out their responsibilities? Do you think that local authorities are responsible for a large proportion of public affairs in your country? Are their financial resources in proportion to their responsibilities? If you cannot draw an overall comparison between responsibilities and financial resources, you might be able to provide an operational expenditure breakdown (for example as a % of the total amount spent on different activities, such as education or social welfare). It would also be useful to have specific examples of discrepancies between the significance of a responsibility and the funds allocated to it. Acts effecting one-off transfers between central government and local authorities may also provide tangible evidence of the approach your country’s legislature or government takes to application of the principle of equivalence between resources and costs.

10. To what extent and according to which criteria are local authorities required to carry out duties on behalf of higher authorities?

11. Please give a detailed list of local and regional authorities’ responsibilities, distinguishing between municipalities and second or third tier authorities (province, département, county, region) which do not enjoy legislative powers (ie excluding federal entities), and grouping them under the headings set out below. Please note that the questionnaire is not set out in table form in order that replies can be given in as much detail as possible.

c. Health

12. Is the way in which local responsibilities are defined currently under discussion? What issues have been raised in that discussion and what are the prospects for change?

2. Classification of responsibilities used in monographs prepared by the CDLR

Functions

Authority responsible

Type of responsibility

 

Basis on which responsibility is exercised

Comments

 

Central
government

Intermediate authority

Municipality

Exclusive

Shared

Mandatory

Optional

Direct

Indirect

On own behalf

For another authority

*

General administration

                       

Security, police

                       

Fire prevention

                       

Civil defence

                       

Justice

                       

Registry office

                       

Statistical office

                       

Electoral register

                       

Education

                       

Pre-school education

                       

Primary education

                       

Secondary education

                       

Vocational and technical education

                       

Higher education

                       

Adult education

                       

Miscellaneous

                       

Public health

                       

Hospitals

                       

Health protection

                       

Social welfare

                       

Crèches and childcare
facilities

                       

Family and youth support

                       

Rest homes

                       

Social security

                       

Miscellaneous

                       

Housing and town
planning

                       

Housing

                       

Town planning

                       

Regional/spatial planning

                       

Environment and public
sanitation

                       

Water treatment

                       

Refuse collection and
disposal

                       

Cemeteries and crematoria

                       

Abattoirs

                       

Environmental protection

                       

Consumer protection

                       

Culture, leisure activities
and sport

                       

Theatres and concert halls

                       

Museums and libraries

                       

Parks and open spaces

                       

Sport and leisure activities

                       

Function

Authority responsible

Type of responsibility

Basis on which responsibility is exercised

Comments

 

Central
government

Intermediate authority

Municipality

Exclusive

Shared

Mandatory

Optional

Direct

Indirect

On own behalf

For another
authority

*

Religious facilities

                       

Miscellaneous

                       

Traffic and transport

                       

Road network

                       

Transport

                       

Urban road transport

                       

Urban rail transport

                       

Ports

                       

Airports

                   

+

 

Miscellaneous

                       

Economic services

                       

Gas

                       

Urban heating

                       

Water

                       

Agriculture, forestry and fisheries

                       

Electricity

                       

Promoting the economy

                       

Trade and industry

                       

Tourism

                       

Miscellaneous

                       

Other functions

                       
1 For the conditions of development of the system, readers should refer to our introductory report to the Barcelona Conference, devoted to the implementation of the Charter by the Law Courts (24 and 26 April 1997). 2 The conclusions of this first report are to be developed in the report presented by Mrs. Doganoglu, the purpose of which is to compare the information gathered by the experts and that contained in the opinion drafted in reply to it by the experts of the CDLR. 3 CPL/LOC/CHARTE (28) 17 rev. 2 "I. Place and procedure for the integration of international law into the legal procedures of the Council of Europe's member states and application to the European Charter of Local Self-Government" 4 Including, in particular, a report drafted with a view to responding to CLRAE Recommendation No. 2 (1994) on monitoring the implementation of the European Charter of Local Self-Government, which was examined on 15 and 16 February 1996, and the CDLR's favourable Opinion submitted to the Committee of Ministers on the procedure proposed in paragraphs 8 and 9 of CLRAE Recommendation No. 20 (1996). 5 Cf. document CPL/Loc (27) PV 3 Prov. 6 Since published in the “Local and regional authorities in Europe” series (No. 61). 7 The methodological problems involved in comparing local finances are considered later in this report. The discussion with the group of experts showed how difficult the task was. Statistics only mean something if they can be compared, but we have to note that there is no common system of compiling statistics in the field of local finances. Rather, there are several systems, each with its own logic, but none of them currently approach the issue of finance from the local self-government viewpoint. 8 It seems that the question of definitions was largely responsible for this. 9 The criterion adopted is that of "public administrations", with the noteworthy exception, however, of the local branches of social security departments, "whose authority covers only part of the economic territory". 10 The OECD has published an interesting series of detailed national accounts for the period 1982-1994, which make a distinction, for each country, between the general accounts of public authorities, those of central government, those of "federal or provincial" governments, those of local authorities and of social security administrations. Unfortunately the series are occasionally incomplete, and the "federal or provincial" government category is not always identified. A curious instance is the absence of the category for Belgium, and its presence for the Netherlands. Also worth noting is the series of statistics on Public Revenue (1965-1995), although they do not always coincide with the data supplied by the experts. 11 Brussels - Paris, July 1997. DEXIA is a joint venture between the Crédit Local de France and the Crédit Communal de Belgique. 12 An instance is the reply from the CDLR dated 11 September 1996 to recommendation no. 2 (1994) which followed on from an initial report drafted by the working group and examined by the Congress. 13 In all likelihood the working group's report will not be available before the next plenary session of the Congress, scheduled for July 1998. 14 As is the case with Switzerland, for example. 15 Explanatory report, p. 17 16 Ibid., p. 17 17 The exact terms of the Charter are that they shall not "diminish the discretion local authorities may exercise within their own sphere of responsibility" (Art. 9-5). 18 As with the case of the German Federal Republic, for instance. 19 The third, fourth and fifth columns correspond to information supplied by CDLR (Report on Local Finances in Europe, no. 61, local and regional authorities in Europe); the sixth and seventh columns contain supplementary reference data provided by the experts appointed to assist the Congress working group, or in the absence of any such data, and for those countries belonging to the European Union, the figures which were included in the DEXIA survey mentioned earlier. The figures in italics correspond to data provided for countries not covered by the CDLR study. 20 If social security expenditure were included, which is reimbursed 100%, Danish municipality expenditure would represent, according to KJ, 26.9% of GDP and 42.3% of GGE 21 KJ decided to include counties in their statistics, claiming that Oslo, which is both a commune and a county, represented alone nearly half the municipality expenditure. 22 Virtually double: from 6.7 to 12% of GDP for 1994. 23 For instance, depending on the country, it may or may not include social security expenditure. We take it to include all public authority budgets (both regional and local) administered by elected representatives and the central Government. 24 For example in Slovenia, the opinion of Professor Smidovnik. The reform of local administration in Slovenia. Directory of local authorities, Paris 1996, p. 157. 25 It is interesting to note that for the latter country the level did not vary between 1984 and 1995. 26 There are analogous although less marked findings in the Hungarian report (where local and regional expenditure dropped as a percentage of general public expenditure from 16.1% in 1995 to 14.12% in 1997). 27 The reference date of 1994 did not allow integration of the reforms that have occurred since. 28 It will be noted that the Charter uses the expression "resources of their own", and not taxes of their own, but it is obvious that the term applies in priority to taxation, which is considered by definition as being the symbol of true self-government. 29 The CDLR goes even further, since they classify them in their tables in the column entitled "exclusive local taxes" (table no. 3), which in this case we find somewhat excessive. 30 Local finance in Europe, p. 41. 31 Belgian specialists in public finance refer to them as "joint taxes". 32 The changes are indicated in italics. For the reference years corresponding to the changes made, please see Table no. 1. 33 Table drawn up on the basis of reports by members of the group of experts, the work by the DEXIA mentioned earlier, and in the absence of any such figures, on the statistics included in the CDLR report. 34 In order to make comparisons easier, at the bottom of the table we have included the average for the figures used by the CDLR. 35 This item is detailed in Chapter VI. 36 An example of this is the tax on the disposal of household rubbish. Also worth noting is the fact that the table includes countries which did not appear in the CDLR table, at least two of which (Lithuania and the former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia) have fairly surprising percentages of local taxes, but which do not seem to likely to be maintained - alas, one might add - if the trend in the other countries is considered. 37 As we shall see in the following chapter, on average, shared taxes only represent a little more than one-fifth of the "transfer" item. 38 Even though the figures for Lithuania and the former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, as we have seen, no doubt artificially inflate the proportion of local taxes. 39 The table is based on data gathered in particular from the experts based on the model table produced by the CDLR, in order to make comparison easier. The key is the same: Tax: mandatory: I, non-mandatory: F - Rate: complete discretion: T, limited discretion (imposed bracket or ceiling): E, prescribed by the State: A 40 In France this corresponds to an administrative assessment. 41 This, of course, is the case with the United Kingdom and Ireland. It is also worth noting, however, that this is also the case in most federal States outside Europe (such as the United States, Canada and Australia). 42 Local tax on business is the primary tax resource for local authorities in France, Luxembourg, Germany and Portugal. 43 Report cited previously, p. 44. 44 That of Portugal, in which the "derrama" is a surtax to the State tax on company earnings. 45 Russia and Malta have just joined the list, but at low and even insignificant levels. The taxes in question are dues paid for the right to exercise a commercial activity (corresponding to the old French concept of a licence). 46 In which the local company tax is divided into two: a tax on employed personnel, and a tax on motor power. 47 But on a relatively limited portion (18% of wages and salaries). 48 From which the local company tax is sometimes deductible (France). 49 Only one third of all companies are taxed, compared with two-thirds in 1975. J. Flejo, Grale/Arcole Directory of local authorities 1997, p. 43. 50 There are two funds, one national, the other at the level of the département. 51 The Danish report noted that it is the local authorities who are accountable for calculating the tax, and that (only?) since 1996, municipalities and counties alike may choose a basis of assessment determined by the central government. 52 It is worth noting that in Iceland, together with its own share the State pays the municipalities a lump sum for each inhabitant exempted from the tax. 53 This is one of the reasons why in the end there was no enforcement of the reform attempting to replace the département portion of the household tax with a tax based on income. The resulting transfers of charges were deemed to be too heavy. 54 Based on our own calculations, the average number of taxes effectively raised in 1991 for the 19 municipalities in the Brussels conurbation was 39, the variance ranging from 28 to 63. 55 In Germany, the beer tax is reserved for the Länder, and forms one of the rare exclusive tax resources. 56 On the other hand, these taxes are increasing in countries where the VAT rate is still low, such as the tax on the sales of computers, alcoholic drinks and insurance in Russia. 57 Although strictly speaking they do not involve property transactions, the same applies to the taxes on buildings (Spain), or the taxes raised in exchange for the construction of a public facility which is of particular benefit to a given category of tax-payer (such as the local tax on civil engineering infrastructures in France). 58 In these cases it is considered a service rendered to the local authorities by the central administration, and paid for as such by deducting a percentage from the amount of tax collected (for "collection and assessment costs"). 59 In Sweden, for instance, the State grant is decreased by a rate equal to half the rate of increase in income tax. 60 On this point, the reader may refer to the previously published report in the collection of studies and documents of the Council of Europe on the "definition and limits of the subsidiarity principle". 61 16% of which is used for financial equalisation. 62 It would perhaps be fairer in this case to speak of a redistributed tax, in that the tax continues to be levied locally but is based on a single rate prescribed by the State. Income from the tax is paid back to the municipalities on the basis of the number of their inhabitants, except for the City of London which is authorised to retain part of the revenue. 63 The Rate Support Grant was introduced from 1958 onwards. It is now called the Revenue Support Grant. 64 The change in government in Malta at the end of 1996 resulted in a drop of 14% in the amount of general grants to local authorities and their replacement by specific grants. 65 This also raises a query about the classification in certain cases performed by the CDLR. According to other sources (DEXIA) 67% of transfers consisted of "allocated grants" (to carry out co-management tasks). In the same way in Belgium, the share of general grants is in effect allocated to providing revenue for a municipal fund, but the criteria for the allocation of resources seems to take significant account of the assessment made by the authorities accountable for the grants (henceforth the regions). 66 It is worth adding to the examples cited above the case of Ireland, where since November 1996 the rate support grant is also designed to replace the local tax on housing and farming land. It is only since this date that the transfer is destined to be used for financial equalisation purposes. 67 The rate is fixed for a four-year period by the domestic legislation, further to consultation with the representative associations. 68 In fact the revenue for this grant is produced by a deduction levied on the wealthiest municipalities. It is not fundamentally different from one of the grants recently introduced in France to equalise tax resources, entitled the urban solidarity grant (dotation de solidarité urbaine [DSU]). 69 The legislator considers that expenditure per capita (and therefore requirements) increase with the size of the municipality. 70 In which the grants are partially pre-allocated (40% for investment, 10% for the parishes). 71 Grants covering current expenditure, however, do not seem to be negligible in a country such as Finland (where they mainly involve social welfare or education). 72 For example the payment by the Luxembourg government of two-thirds of the salaries for primary school teachers and policemen, who, although employed locally, are civil servants. 73 12.24% according to our figures, 11.72% according to the CDLR. 74 The CDLR arrived at an average of 12.14%. For certain countries the "Other" item is still too high (25.48% for Turkey, which is an exception in this case) and merits further explanation. 75 Up to 2/3 of such investments in France and in Germany, for example. 76 This questionnaire and the second one are appended to the present report. 77 A certain amount of information was also obtained concerning three countries not covered in the answers to the questionnaires: Poland, Slovakia and the Czech Republic. 78 The studies produced by the CDLR are only of limited assistance in this respect. While the new series contains a more detailed classification, the headings used do not tally with those of the old series, which covered many more countries. 79 This requirement is closely reflected in the current concern with the application of the subsidiarity principle. 80 Decisions of the French Constitutional Council Nos 82-146 DC, of 25 March 1982, and 85-186 DC, of 8 August 1985. Judgment of the German Federal Constitutional Court of 31 October 1990. 81 The new Polish Constitution confines itself to a general principle for defining local responsibilities: “Local self-government shall perform public tasks not reserved by the Constitution or statutes to the organs of other public authorities.” (Article 163). 82 See, for example, Article 163 of the new Polish Constitution cited in the previous footnote. 83 Ireland, however, has recently departed from this tradition. 84 C.M.G. Himsworth, CPL/GT/CEAL (5) 10, page 5. 85 Sean O’Riordain, in A. Delcamp, Les collectivités décentralisées de l’Union Européenne, Paris, La Documentation Française, 1994, p. 230. 86 Judgment of 31 October 1990, cited above. 87 For further detail, see below. 88 Article 4.5 (delegated responsibilities): “Where powers are delegated to them by a central or regional authority, local authorities shall, insofar as possible, be allowed discretion in adapting their exercise to local conditions.” 89 Which is why in Belgian legal theory they are also termed “special responsibilities” (probably by analogy with the speciality rule referred to above, which - as we have
seen - does not govern the activities of local authorities).
90 See our previous reports, particularly the first one. 91 This form of decentralisation on a territorial basis contrasts with what is sometimes termed (wrongly in our view) “decentralisation by service”. 92 Article 85.1: “Where the States execute federal statutes as agents of the Federation, the establishment of the requisite authorities remains the concern of the States, except insofar as federal statutes consented to by the Senate otherwise provide.” 93 See the second report, on supervision. 94 Study Series Local & Regional Authorities in Europe, No. 55. 95 And thus to the allocation of functions between the public and private sectors. 96 Our emphasis. 97 This is also the perspective of Recommendation R (95) 19 of the Committee of Ministers on the implementation of the principle of subsidiarity, which was based on the study quoted above and was also the object of a Congress Opinion, drafted by the Working Group on the Charter. 98 The Latin word “subsidium” can also mean “aid”. 99 The German “Kreise” are sometimes regarded as part of the local tier of government although, in fact, they constitute an intermediate level of decentralisation between the municipalities and the federated states. 100 As far as we are aware, ratification of the Charter has not occasioned any constitutional revision in those countries that have been members of the Council of Europe for longest. 101 An ambiguity dealt with in II above. 102 The French Act of 2 March 1982 on the rights and freedoms of municipalities, départements and regions is also essentially “procedural” but it includes provisions on local government powers in the field of economic affairs. There are two laws (of 7 January and 22 July 1983) governing the allocation of responsibilities, which contain provisions in respect of town planning, social action, culture and transport. A third act provides for the allocation of responsibilities in the field of education. 103 Even the French Commission supérieure de codification decided not to include a section on responsibilities in the general local government code. 104 This applies essentially to Germany, where the trend is all the more marked because the state has been federal since its inception. The problems are different in the case of former unitary states that have gone through a phase of regionalisation (Spain and Italy, for example), or indeed federalisation (the case of Belgium). 105 Local and regional authorities in Europe, No. 55. 106 Vivre ensemble, Paris, La Documentation Française, 1976, p. 97. 107 With the notable exceptions of Germany and Austria. 108 Despite the fact that the effect in these countries of the gradual and substantial decentralisation of educational responsibilities since 1995 is not reflected here. 109 The bold-type figures in brackets also show how the different responsibilities rank at each level. 110 Total government-supported expenditure in Scotland only. 111 Administration. 112 Civil defence and fire service. 113 Administration. 114 Also includes culture. 115 Care of the elderly (14,7) and the young (13,8). 116 Within which social security accounts for 21,5%. 117 Within which sickness insurance accounts for 16.5%. 118 Also includes housing. (1) Vocational training and lycées 119 Budget of Tallinn. 120 Based on budgets of average-sized municipalities. 121 “Primary communes”ie municipalities and “departmental communes” (or counties). 122 General administration. 123 Administration. 124 General administration. 125 Administration. (1) Roads (operational and plant costs). (2) 16,2 % operational and 13,9 % plant costs. 126 Water, electricity and housing. 127 All municipal services: water, drains, roads, lighting and public works. 128 For example, by imposing taxes or charging for services - these being the two main types of own resources. See, on this question, the last section of the report on finances. 129 Determining criteria for comparison is also hazardous because it can result in the imposition of a standard approach, at odds with the devolved decision-making that is the logical product of decentralisation. 130 The comment by Dr Artashes Gazaryan (Lithuania) is worth quoting here, that “in most cases, local authorities nowadays can only deal with those problems for which central government funding is available, because local government in Lithuania does not have its own resources”. (CPL/GT/CELA (4) 11, p. 2). 131 Coverage of the recent demonstrations by lycée students in France highlighted the effort that has been made by the regions since they were given responsibility for the lycées in 1986. The leaders of the regional authorities pointed out that in 1988 alone the regions had spent FF 11 billion more than the FF 18 billion allocated to them by the state to cover this slice of their budget. 132 For example, through a provision along the following lines: “Any new transfer of responsibilities to local government must be accompanied by a corresponding transfer of resources” or “must be preceded by a report on the financial consequences for the authorities in question”. 133 Many delegations of powers are the result of the legislation of federated or quasi-federated states (eg the Autonomous Communities in Spain or the Italian regions). 134 For example, local authorities, under their own responsibility and in the framework of their elected councils shall manage a substantial set of public responsibilities which, because of their link with the area concerned and its development, or their indirect influence on the day-to-day life of the population, should be decided at local level. They shall also manage all other areas of competence assigned to them by law. 135 For example, with regard to the right to build, which authority has the power to draw up the municipality's local land use plan, and which authority (if it is a different one) issues actual planning permission? Similarly, with regard to education, indicate whether municipalities are responsible for the construction of buildings, building maintenance, the remuneration and recruitment of teachers, the curriculum, and so on.